Predatory pricing

Predatory pricing is a pricing strategy, using the method of undercutting on a larger scale, where a dominant firm in an industry will deliberately reduce its prices of a product or service to loss-making levels in the short-term.[1] The aim is that existing or potential competitors within the industry will be forced to leave the market, as they will be unable to effectively compete with the dominant firm without making a loss.[2] Once competition has been eliminated, the dominant firm now with having a majority share of the market can then raise their prices to monopoly levels in the long-term to recoup their losses.[3]

The difference between predatory pricing and competitive pricing is during the recouping phase of lost profits by the dominant firm charging higher prices. With there being fewer firms in the market causing consumers to have fewer choices between these products or services these higher prices results in consumer harm.[4] Predatory pricing usually will cause consumer harm and is considered anti-competitive in many jurisdictions making the practice illegal under some competition laws.

Concept

Predatory pricing is split into a two-stage strategy.

First stage, is the predation, where the dominant firm offers a good or service at a below-cost rate, which reduces the firm's immediate profits in the short-term. This drop in price forces the price market for those goods or services to readjust to this lower price as an equilibrium, putting smaller firms and industry entrants at risk of closing and leaving the industry. The principle of this method is the dominant firm has the size and capital to sustain the short-term loss in profits, unlike new entrants and current players, thus forcing a game of survival that the dominant firm will normally win.[5]

Second stage, is the recoupment, where the dominant firm readjusts its product and service prices close to monopoly prices (or monopoly price, depending on remaining industry players and the dominant firm's market share) to recover their losses in the long-term. This price adjustment can put consumers under pressure, as they are now forced to absorb it without the competition to offer a better price, resulting in consumer harm. This is what separates predatory price from normal competitive pricing.[6] Under EU law, the European Commission can account for recoupment as a factor in determining whether predatory pricing is abusive.[7] This is because predatory pricing can only be economically effective if a firm can recover its short-term losses from pricing below average variable costs (AVC).[8] However, recoupment is not a precondition for establishing whether predatory pricing is an abuse of dominance under Article 102 TFEU.[9] Assessing other factors, such as barriers to entry, can suffice to prove how the predatory pricing could foreclose competitors from the market.[10]

The use of predatory pricing to capture a market in one territory while maintaining high prices in the suppliers' home market (also known as "dumping") creates a risk that the loss-making product will find its way back to the home market and drive down prices there. For example, when Dow Chemical exported competitively-priced bromine to Europe, the established German bromine cartel attempted to punish them by selling bromine in the US at half price (below manufacturing cost), which would prevent Dow from making any profit in the US. But Dow's founder Herbert Dow simply purchased the cheap German product and sold it back to Europe at a profit. Eventually the cartel worked out what was happening and ceased dumping their product, but by then Dow's company had acquired a base of customers in Europe and his US competitors had been forced out of business.[11]

1. The principal part of predatory pricing is the operator in the seller's market, and the operator has certain economic or technical strength. This feature distinguishes it from price discrimination, which includes not only competition between sellers but also competition among buyers.

2. The geographical market of predatory pricing is the country's domestic market. This feature distinguishes it from "dumping". "Dumping" refers to the act of selling commodities in overseas markets at a lower price than the domestic market. It can be seen that these two have similarities in terms of "low-cost sales" and "exhaustion of competitors", but their differences are obvious.

(1) The scopes of application of the two are different. "Predatory pricing" applies to domestic trade, and "dumping" applies to international trade. ( 2) The standards for the identification of the two are different. "Predatory pricing" is based on cost, while "dumping" is based on the price applicable to the normal trading of domestic similar products.

(3) The laws applicable to both are different. "Predatory pricing" mainly applies to domestic laws, while "dumping" mainly applies to international treaties or the laws of other countries.

(4) The consequences of the two are different. Legal sanctions on “predatory pricing” are compensating damages or administrative penalties, while “dumping” is levying anti-dumping duties.

3. The objective performance of predatory pricing is a company temporarily sells goods or services below cost. Its essence is that it temporarily loses money, but squeezes competitors out of a certain market to form an exclusive situation. Then the predatory pricing company can sell goods and services at monopoly prices to make up for the losses from its low price sales.

4. A dominant firm's subjective intention may be to eliminate competition to gain a monopoly advantage. Under EU law, if a dominant firm prices above AVC but below average total costs (ATC), proving intention can be useful evidence for a finding of predatory pricing.[12] However, it can be difficult to distinguish an intention to eliminate competitors from a legitimate intention to win competition.[13] Therefore, the European Commission do not have to establish an undertaking's subjective intention to show Article 102 applies, especially as abuse is an “objective” rather than a subjective concept.[14]

Implementation conditions

1.Sacrificing short-term profits

The economic theory of predatory pricing simply states that companies choose to make less profitable pricing in the short term, but it does not explicitly state that profits must be negative. In anti-monopoly law enforcement, how to determine what level of pricing is predatory pricing becomes a problem in operation. In the anti-monopoly law enforcement, a clear standard is: During the period of predatory prices, the predator's profit is negative, or the price is lower than the cost. But the question here is what kind of cost can be used as a reference. The use of a price that is lower than the cost may make certain predatory pricing practices not legally binding. According to the theory of industrial organization, some predatory pricing practices may not lose money in the short term. However, in this particular case, the company's ability to make low-cost profits can only indicate that the company is a high-efficiency company compared to its competitors. Non-entry of entrants does not necessarily reduce benefits, and entry of entrants does not necessarily improve welfare. Anti-monopoly law ignores this and does not result in major welfare losses. In summary, although below-cost pricing does not summarize all predatory pricing practices, the cost of law enforcement mistakes it brings along may be very small.

2. The ability of incumbent company to raise prices

An important condition for predatory pricing is that a dominant firm can raise prices after excluding competitors to compensate for their short-term losses. To achieve this, market power can be an important factor. However, under EU law, market power is not necessary to establish predatory pricing,[15] since other factors such as barriers to entry can indicate an abuse of a dominant position.[16]

Theories for controlling predatory pricing

It can be difficult to identify when normal price competition turns into anti-competitive predatory pricing.[17] Therefore, various rules and economic tests have been established to identify predatory pricing.

No rule

Especially according to Easterbrook predatory pricing is rare, thus it should not be a central concern. Introducing laws for predation, especially because it is rare, could lead to generating false positive errors, which would interplay with the restriction of the rule. The main point within this argument is that government intervention is dispensable, as predation is unlikely to succeed, which creates a deterrent. This effect results by selling the products/services below the costs, which causes losses but without getting more market power. The market power doesn't increase in this case, because the market share holder weathers this predatory strategy. Thus, the firm punished itself by taking losses without gaining market. This is a deterrent for other firms. An additional argument against the implementation of rules is the inability of courts or competition authorities to differentiate predatory from competitive prices.[18]

Short-run cost-based rules

In 1975, Phillip Areeda and Donald Turner developed a short-run cost-based test, widely referred to as the ‘Areeda-Turner rule’.[19] The rules are based on short term focus, even when the predatory-pricing strategy is a long-term strategy, because the long run would be inefficient, as it would be too speculative. The Areeda-Turner rule suggests prices at or above reasonable expected average variable costs (AVC) are presumed to be lawful, but prices below AVC are presumed to be unlawful and anti-competitive.[20]

In EU law, the approach to testing for predatory pricing under Article 102 has been explained in a number of important cases.

In ECS/AKZO, the European Commission did not adopt the Areeda-Turner rule.[21] The Court of Justice upheld this decision because other factors should also be considered alongside a cost-based analysis, such as plans that prove the dominant firm intended to eliminate competition.[22] Instead, the Court in AKZO suggested that if a dominant firm sets prices below AVC, the predatory pricing is presumed to be predatory and abusive because the intention is to eliminate competitors rather than to maximise profits.[23] If a dominant firm sets prices above AVC but below ATC, this is not presumed to be predatory but could be proven if there is evidence it is part of the dominant firm's plan to eliminate competition.[24] If a dominant firm sets prices above ATC, it is usually not guilty of predatory pricing but this may be proven to be anti-competitive if it could lead to substantial consumer harm.[25] The AKZO test was reaffirmed in Tetra Pak II,[26] and France Télécom.[27]

In Post Danmark I, the Court of Justice developed upon AKZO by holding prices above average incremental costs but below ATC would unlikely be abusive under Article 102 if there was no evidence the dominant firm deliberately intended to eliminate competition.[28]

Long term cost-based rule

The long term cost-based rule is established by Posner. He assumes that long-run marginal costs are a more reliable test of predation than short run costs. The reason is that the predator (who prices at short-run marginal cost), could eliminate a competitor who can't afford losses in the short run. Posner argues too, that because of the hard determination of marginal costs, he would substitute average costs from the firm's balance sheet to establish a test that relates to the full average costs based on the company's books. The test would include certain prerequisites, an intent element, as well as a defence. As a prerequisite Posner requires the plaintiff to demonstrate that the market was predestined for effective predatory pricing.[29] As indicators Posner lists for instance that the predator operates in various markets, whereas the prey operates in less markets; concentrated market; slow entry; few fringe firms; homogenous products, numerous buyers. Posner would authorize the firm to defend because of changes in supply or demand, so that the respondent firm could price its products at short run marginal cost.[30]

According to the European Commission's 'Guidance in Applying Article 102', if a dominant firm does not cover its average avoidable costs or long-run average incremental costs, this implies the dominant firm is operating at a loss in the short-term to foreclose equally efficient competitors from the market.[31] The Guidance does not bind the EU Courts,[32] but it is an important document that could influence future decisions.[33]

Rules governing price increases after predation

William Baumol proposed a long-term rule, seeking to avoid full reliance on cost-based tests.[34] Baumol's rule would require any price cut made in response to entry to continue for a five-year period after exit (i.e., if an incumbent firm cuts its price to drive out an entrant, the incumbent firm is prevented from increasing price for five years).[35] This rule significantly diminishes the incentive of a firm to engage in predatory pricing, since the predatory firm can't reap the benefits of their anti-competitive behavior (monopoly profits). Baumol's proposed rule is not absolute, however. Baumol offers the predator some freedom to raise its post-exit price if the price increase is justified (e.g., by demonstrable changes in the firm's costs or market demand).[36]

Further strategies

→Output expansion rules by Williamson Forsyth Peter [37] →Industry- specific rules by Craswell and Fratrik[38] →Rule of reason tests by Scherer [39] →Two-tier rules by Josko wand Klevorick [40]

In many countries there are legal restrictions upon using this pricing strategy, which may be deemed anti-competitive. It may not be technically illegal, but have severe restrictions.

Australia

Predatory pricing is illegal in Australia, the Trade Practices Act made the point of stating that the dominant firm has to have a significant quantity of the market share within the industry the dominant operates. The definition of what predatory prices in the Act states that the dominant firm has to employ the method of undercutting or underselling with the intention to force competitors or prevent entry to the industry. The dominant firm can only have significant quantity of market share to the industry if the firm is not substantially impacted or constrained by its competitors on suppliers and consumers.[41]

In 2007, amendments to the Trade Practices Act 1974 created a new threshold test to prohibit those engaging in predatory pricing. The amendments, labelled the 'Birdsville Amendments' after Senator Barnaby Joyce, penned the idea[42] in s46 to define the practice more liberally than other behavior by requiring the business first to have a 'substantial share of a market' (rather than substantial market power). This was made in a move to protect smaller businesses from situations where there are larger players, but each has market power.

Canada

Section 50 of the Competition Act, which criminalized predatory pricing, has been repealed[43] and replaced by sections 78 and 79, which deal with the matters civilly.

Section 78(1)(i)[44] of the Competition Act prohibits companies from the selling products at unreasonably low prices designed to facilitate or with the effect of eliminating competition or a competitor. The Competition Bureau has established Predatory Pricing Guidelines defining what is considered unreasonably low pricing.

United States

Predatory pricing practices may result in antitrust claims of monopolization or attempts to monopolize. Businesses with dominant or substantial market shares are more vulnerable to antitrust claims. However, because the antitrust laws are ultimately intended to benefit consumers, and discounting results in at least short-term net benefit to consumers, the U.S. Supreme Court has set high hurdles to antitrust claims based on a predatory pricing theory. The Court requires plaintiffs to show a likelihood that the pricing practices affect not only rivals, but also competition in the market as a whole—to establish there is a substantial probability of success of the attempt to monopolize.[45] If there is a likelihood that market entrants will prevent the predator from recouping its investment through supra competitive pricing, then there is no probability of success and the antitrust claim would fail. In addition, the Court established that for prices to be predatory, they must be below the seller's cost.

The US Department of Justice, however, claims that modern economic theory based on strategic analysis supports predatory pricing as a real problem, and claims that the courts are out of date and too skeptical.[46]

European Union

Article 102 of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union is the relevant statutory provision under EU law for dealing with predatory pricing. According to Article 102:

“Any abuse by one or more undertakings of a dominant position within the internal market or in a substantial part of it shall be prohibited as incompatible with the internal market in so far as it may affect trade between Member States.” [47]

If Article 102 is breached by a predatory pricing practice, the European Commission may intervene as they prioritise dealing with “exclusionary abuses” which exclude competitors from the market.[48]  According to the 'Guidance in Applying Article 102', the Commission normally intervene in possible predatory pricing cases if a dominant firm aims to maintain or strengthen its market power by "sacrificing" short-term losses to foreclose “as efficient” competitors,[49] or even “less efficient” competitors.[50] The "as efficient competitor" refers to a hypothetical competitor with the same costs as the dominant firm.[51] The "as efficient competitor" test was endorsed in AKZO as the legal standard for assessing predatory pricing under Article 102.[52]

India

The Competition Act, 2002 outlaws predatory pricing, treating it as an abuse of dominant position, prohibited under Section 4. Predatory pricing under the Act means the sale of goods or provision of services, at a price below cost, as may be determined by regulations, of production of the goods or provision of services, with a view to reduce competition or eliminate the competitors.[53]

Russian Federation

Article 10 of the Federal Law No.135-FZ ‘On the Protection of Competition’ (FLPC) (Russian: ст. 10, Федерального закона от 26.07.2006 N 135-ФЗ "О защите конкуренции") deals with unilateral conduct of economic entities by prohibiting abuse of dominant position. The definition of such abuse, as stated in the article, includes "the setting of an unjustified high or unjustified low price of a financial service by a financial entity".[54]

All the matters connected with the abuse of the market power are handled by the Federal Antimonopoly Service of Russian Federation (FAS). The FAS investigates all alleged violations of the antimonopoly legislation and determines whether a dominant position has been exploited by one of the market participants.

The United Kingdom

Section 18(1) of the Competition Act 1998 prohibits the abuse of a dominant position by 'one or more undertakings ... if it may affect trade within the United Kingdom’.[55] This is commonly known as the ‘Chapter II prohibition’. The section is very similar to article 102 of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union governing the anti-monopoly laws within the EU jurisdiction, with the exception of parts regarding the effect on trade within the UK.

Germany

Sections 19 and 20 of the Act against Restraints of Competition (ARC) prohibit the abuse of a dominant position. Section 19 lists in more detail the entities with market power addressed by the Act. Article 102 of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union also applies, although it has some differences with the ARC.

Compliance with the Act is enforced by the German Federal Cartel Office (FCO) (German: Bundeskartellamt). With the FCO as the higher federal authority, there also exist state cartels in each of the federal states in Germany. The FCO is in the area of responsibility of the Federal Ministry for Economic Affairs and Energy (German: Bundesministerium für Wirtschaft und Energie).

Austria

The European competition law art. 82 EC and § 5 KartG 2005 prohibit a market dominant enterprise, as well as a collective of several dominant enterprises, which intentionally suppressing a competitor or increasing their respective market share by using methods other than those of legal competitive performance.[56] According to the law predatory pricing is in the one hand given if the market-dominat enterprise or enterprises controlling the local market, because it offers their products at prices, below their own average variable costs. In the other hand if the prices are below average total costs (fixed plus variable costs) but above average variable costs. If the market abuse is directed against the competitors, and not against suppliers and clients, the Austrian law provides provisions under § 1UWG (in connection with §5 para. 1 KartG 2005, if there is a competitive relationship) [57] Furthermore, according to §1UWG predatory pricing can be unconscionable if intended to harm competitors—even without the dominant company incurring losses. Moreover, predatory pricing can be unconscionable according to §1UWG if the dominant firm expels enough competitors from the market to gain enough market share to dictate prices.[58]

Denmark

According to §6, sec. 1, of the Competition Act (CA) entering into of anti-competitive agreements is prohibited. The CA §6 corresponds to art. 81, sec. 1 of the EC- Treaty and prohibit predatory pricing.[59]

Greece

Generally, Art. 1 (1) of the antitrust law (I. 703/1977) prohibits all agreements between undertakings, decisions by associations of undertakings, and concerted practices that strive to prevent, restrict, or distort competition in the Greek market.[60] Particularly art. 2(1) of I 703/77 prohibits predatory pricing within Greece.

Sweden

According to Art. 81 of the EC Treaty and sec. 6 of the Swedish Competition Act (KL) agreements between undertakings, which have as their issue or effect to distort competition is prohibited. Thus agreements regarding prices are prohibited per se.

Criticism

Some economists claim that true predatory pricing is a rare phenomenon claiming it is an irrational practice and that laws designed to prevent it only inhibit competition.[61] According to the European Commission, this is because predatory pricing can cause firms to make a loss due to increased output.[62] This stance was taken by the US Supreme Court in the 1993 case Brooke Group v. Brown & Williamson Tobacco, and the Federal Trade Commission has not successfully prosecuted any company for predatory pricing since.

Thomas Sowell explains one reason why predatory pricing may not be completely effective:

Obviously, predatory pricing pays off only if the surviving predator can then raise prices enough to recover the previous losses, making enough extra profit thereafter to justify the risks. These risks are not small.
However, even the demise of a competitor does not leave the survivor home free. Bankruptcy does not by itself destroy the fallen competitor's physical plant or the people whose skills made it a viable business. Both may be available-perhaps at distress prices-to others who can spring up to take the defunct firm's place.
The Washington Post went bankrupt in 1933, though not because of predatory pricing. But neither its physical plant, its people, or its name disappeared into thin air. Instead, publisher Eugene Meyer acquired all three-at a fraction of what he had bid unsuccessfully for the same newspaper just four years earlier. In the course of time, the Post became the biggest newspaper in Washington.[63]

Critics of laws against predatory pricing may support their case empirically by arguing that there has been no instance where such a practice has actually led to a monopoly.[64] Conversely, they argue that there is much evidence that predatory pricing has failed miserably. For example, Herbert Dow not only found a cheaper way to produce bromine but also defeated a predatory pricing attempt by the government-supported German cartel Bromkonvention, who objected to his selling in Germany at a lower price. Bromkonvention retaliated by flooding the US market with below-cost bromine, at an even lower price than Dow's. However, Dow simply instructed his agents to buy up at the very low price and then sell it back in Germany at a profit but still lower than Bromkonvention's price. In the end, the cartel could not keep up selling below cost and had to give in. That is used as evidence that the free market is a better way to stop predatory pricing than regulations such as anti-trust laws.

In another example of a successful defense against predatory pricing, a price war emerged between the New York Central Railroad (NYCR) and the Erie Railroad. At one point, NYCR charged only a dollar per car for the transport of cattle. While the cattle cars quickly filled up, management were dismayed to find that Erie Railroad had also invested in the cattle-haulage business, making Erie a buyer of cattle transport, and was thus profiting from NYCR's losses.[65]

Sowell argues:

It is a commentary on the development of antitrust law that the accused must defend himself, not against actual evidence of wrongdoing, but against a theory which predicts wrongdoing in the future. It is the civil equivalent of "preventive detention" in criminal cases—punishment without proof.[63]

Support

An article written by heterodox economist Thomas DiLorenzo and published by the libertarian Cato Institute suggests that while a company might be able to successfully price other firms out of the market, there is no evidence to support the theory that the virtual monopoly could then raise prices since other firms would rapidly be able to enter the market and compete.[61] Such entering demands substantial capital investments, which would not be repaid for a long time because of sharp price decreases, provoked by resumption of competition.[66][67]

According to the Chicago school of thought advocated by Bork, predatory pricing is not always anti-competitive even if it ends up being a successful strategy.[68] The Court in Post Danmark agreed predatory pricing does not always harm competition because competing “on the merits” to exclude less-efficient competitors can benefit consumers by providing lower prices and improved quality and choice of products and services.[69]

The DG Competition's 'Discussion Paper' states predatory pricing can be justified as a rational strategy.[70] This is why dominant firms can rebut presumptions of predatory pricing, despite prices falling below the “relevant cost benchmark”. For example, dominant undertakings could argue changing market conditions causing reduced demand but increased capacity meant below-cost pricing was necessary in the short-term to sell off fresh produce.[71] Whilst this defence normally cannot be raised because predatory pricing is rarely the most efficient option, predatory pricing can still be a rational strategy.[72]

Examples of alleged predatory pricing

  • In AKZO v Commission, AKZO were fined €10 million for abusing its dominant position in the organic peroxides market by reducing its prices to loss-making levels, preventing English firm ‘ECS’ from competing on the polymer market.[73]
  • In Tetra Pak v Commission, Tetra Pak were fined €75 million for abusing its dominant position by reducing prices of non-asceptic cartons.[74]
  • In Wanadoo Interactive, a €10.35 million fine was imposed on France Télécom's subsidiary, Wanadoo Interactive.[75] Based on AKZO, high-speed residential broadband internet services were priced at levels below AVC until August 2001, and later at around AVC but below ATC.[76]
  • According to an AP article[77] a law in Minnesota forced Walmart to increase its price for a one-month supply of the prescription birth control pill Tri-Sprintec from $9.00 to $26.88.
  • According to a New York Times article[78] the German government ordered Walmart to increase its prices.
  • According to an International Herald Tribune article,[79] the French government ordered amazon.com to stop offering free shipping to its customers because it violated French predatory pricing laws. After Amazon refused to obey the order, the government proceeded to fine them €1,000 per day. Amazon continued to pay the fines instead of ending its policy of offering free shipping. After a law was created explicitly banning free shipping, Amazon effectively snubbed it by charging one cent for delivery.[80]
  • In the Darlington Bus War, Stagecoach Group offered free bus rides to put the rival Darlington Corporation Transport out of business.[81][82][83][84]
  • Amazon used predatory pricing to undercut competitors like Quidsi before offering to buy out the competitors which then has a bleak future, for cheap.[85]

See also

References

  1. "Glossary of Statistical Terms". OECD. January 3, 2002. Retrieved April 22, 2020.
  2. "Guidance on the Commission's Enforcement Priorities in Applying Article 82 of the EC Treaty to Abusive Exclusionary Conduct by Dominant Undertakings". European Commission. February 24, 2009. Paragraph 63. Retrieved April 22, 2020.
  3. "Predatory Pricing" (PDF). OECD. 1989. Retrieved April 22, 2020.
  4. FDIC Consumer Compliance Examination Manual (PDF). June 2019. pp. II - 2.1.
  5. Funk, Michael (25 July 2018). "The More Economic Approach To Predatory Pricing". Journal of Competition Law & Economic. 14(2): 292–310 via Advanced Access publication.
  6. Ursic, Micaheal L. (1994). "Using Price as a Weapon: An Economic and Legal Analysis of Predatory Pricing". Industrial Marketing Management. 23: 125–131 via Elsevier Science Inc.
  7. Case 202/07 P, France Télécom SA v Commission of the European Communities [2009] ECR I-02369, para 111
  8. Case 62/86, AKZO Chemie BV v Commission of the European Communities [1991] ECR I-03359, para 71
  9. Case 333/94 P, Tetra Pak International SA v Commission of the European Communities [1996] ECR I-5951, para 44
  10. "Guidance on the Commission's Enforcement Priorities in Applying Article 82 of the EC Treaty to Abusive Exclusionary Conduct by Dominant Undertakings". European Commission. February 24, 2009. Paragraph 71. Retrieved April 22, 2020.
  11. Burton W. Folsom (May 1, 1998). "Herbert Dow and Predatory Pricing". Foundation for Economic Education.
  12. Case 62/86, AKZO Chemie BV v Commission of the European Communities [1991] ECR I-03359, para 72
  13. Wanadoo Interactive (Case COMP/38.233) Commission decision of 16 July 2003, para 271
  14. Case 85/76, Hoffmann-La Roche & Co. AG v Commission of the European Communities [1979] ECR II-00461, para 91
  15. Ekaterina, Rousseva (2010). Rethinking Exclusionary Abuses in EU Competition Law. Hart Publishing. p. 408. ISBN 9781841139265.
  16. "Guidance on the Commission's Enforcement Priorities in Applying Article 82 of the EC Treaty to Abusive Exclusionary Conduct by Dominant Undertakings". European Commission. February 24, 2009. Paragraph 71. Retrieved April 22, 2020.
  17. Jones, Alison; Sufrin, Brenda; Dunne, Niamh (2019). Jones & Sufrin's EU Competition Law: Text, Cases, and Materials. Oxford University Press. p. 398. ISBN 9780198824657.
  18. Easterbrook, Predatory Strategies, supra note 1 at 264, 333-37
  19. Areeda, Phillip; Turner, Donald (1975). "Predatory Pricing and Related Practices under Section 2 of the Sherman Act". Harvard Law Review. 88 (4): 697–733. doi:10.2307/1340237. JSTOR 1340237.
  20. Areeda, Phillip; Turner, Donald (1975). "Predatory Pricing and Related Practices under Section 2 of the Sherman Act". Harvard Law Review. 88 (4): 697–733. doi:10.2307/1340237. JSTOR 1340237.
  21. ECS/AKZO (IV/30.698) Commission decision of 14 December 1985, para 76
  22. Case 62/86, AKZO Chemie BV v Commission of the European Communities [1991] ECR I-03359, para 65
  23. Case 62/86, AKZO Chemie BV v Commission of the European Communities [1991] ECR I-03359, para 71
  24. Case 62/86, AKZO Chemie BV v Commission of the European Communities [1991] ECR I-03359, para 72
  25. ECS/AKZO (IV/30.698) Commission decision of 14 December 1985, para 79
  26. Case 333/94 P, Tetra Pak International SA v Commission of the European Communities [1996] ECR I-5951, para 41
  27. Case 202/07 P, France Télécom SA v Commission of the European Communities [2009] ECR I-2369, para 8
  28. Case 209/10, Post Danmark A/S v Konkurrencerådet [2012] EU:C:2012:172, para 44
  29. Richard A. Posner, Antitrust Law. An economic Perspective (University of Chicago Press, 1976), 189
  30. Richard Posner, Antitrust Law: An Economic Perspective 189-190 (1976)
  31. "Guidance on the Commission's Enforcement Priorities in Applying Article 82 of the EC Treaty to Abusive Exclusionary Conduct by Dominant Undertakings". European Commission. February 24, 2009. Paragraph 26. Retrieved April 22, 2020.
  32. Case C-23/14, Post Danmark A/S v Konkurrencerådet EU:C:2015:651, para 52
  33. Whish, Richard; Bailey, David (2018). Competition Law. Oxford University Press. p. 763. ISBN 9780198779063.
  34. William J. Baumol, „Predation and the logic of the average variable cost test“, journal of law and economics vol 39, No 1 (1996)
  35. Quasi -Permanence of Price Reductions: A Policy for Prevention of Predatory Pricing, 89 Yale Law Journal 1 (1979).
  36. Raimundas Moisejevas, Ana Novosad, Virginijus Bitė, supra note 31: 592.
  37. Oliver E Williamson, The Meachanisms of governance ;Oxford university press 291 (1996)
  38. Richard Craswell and Mark Fratrik, Predatory Price Theory Applied: The Case of Supermarkets vs. Warehouse Stores, 36 Case Western Reserve Law Review 1 (1986)
  39. F.M. Sherer, Predatory Pricing and the Sherman Act: A Comment, 89 Harvard Law Review
  40. Paul Joskow and Alvin Klevorik, A Framework for Analysing Predatory Pricing Policy, 89 Yale Law Journal 213 (1979)
  41. "Predatory Price". Australian Competition and Consumer Commission Update. 2005. Retrieved 1 November 2020.
  42. Predatory pricing laws shock big operators, ABC Australia, 2007-10-04, retrieved 2009-03-16
  43. "Competition Act (R.S.C., 1985, c. C-34)". laws-lois.justice.gc.ca. Archived from the original on 2011-07-16.
  44. "Definition of anti-competitive act". Competition Act (R.S.C., 1985, c. C-34). Department of Justice.
  45. Brooke Group Ltd. v. Brown & Williamson Tobacco Corp., 113 S. Ct. 2578, 2589, 209, 1993
  46. "Predatory Pricing: Strategic Theory and Legal Policy". Department of Justice.
  47. "Consolidated Version of the Treaty on European Union and the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union [2008] OJ C115/01, Article 102". May 9, 2008. Retrieved April 22, 2020.
  48. "Guidance on the Commission's Enforcement Priorities in Applying Article 82 of the EC Treaty to Abusive Exclusionary Conduct by Dominant Undertakings". European Commission. February 24, 2009. Paragraph 7. Retrieved April 22, 2020.
  49. "Guidance on the Commission's Enforcement Priorities in Applying Article 82 of the EC Treaty to Abusive Exclusionary Conduct by Dominant Undertakings". European Commission. February 24, 2009. Paragraph 23. Retrieved April 22, 2020.
  50. "Guidance on the Commission's Enforcement Priorities in Applying Article 82 of the EC Treaty to Abusive Exclusionary Conduct by Dominant Undertakings". European Commission. February 24, 2009. Paragraph 24. Retrieved April 22, 2020.
  51. Jones, Alison; Sufrin, Brenda; Dunne, Niamh (2019). Jones & Sufrin's EU Competition Law: Text, Cases, and Materials. Oxford University Press. p. 374. ISBN 9780198824657.
  52. Case 62/86, AKZO Chemie BV v Commission of the European Communities [1991] ECR I-03359, para 72
  53. "Manupatra Articles". www.manupatrafast.com. Retrieved 2016-12-12.
  54. "Статья 10. Запрет на злоупотребление хозяйствующим субъектом доминирующим положением / КонсультантПлюс". www.consultant.ru. Retrieved 2018-04-28.
  55. "Competition Act 1998". www.legislation.gov.uk. Retrieved 2018-04-28.
  56. (OGH 9.10.2000,ÖBI 2001,135 – subscription prices ; OGH 16.12.2002, 16 Ok 11/02 –Red Bull)
  57. OGH 9.9.1997,36 –film hire;OGH 17.3.1998,ÖBI 1998,356.
  58. OGH 10.7.2001 ÖBI 2001,127 best offer
  59. Ejler Bruun at al., Fogedsager (2nd edn 2000), pp 635 et seq., B, von Eyben et. AL., Karnovs Lovssamling (2001) p. 3944
  60. Art 1(1) of I. 703/1977
  61. Thomas DiLorenzo. "The Myth of Predatory Pricing". Cato Institute. Archived from the original on February 23, 1997.
  62. "Guidance on the Commission's Enforcement Priorities in Applying Article 82 of the EC Treaty to Abusive Exclusionary Conduct by Dominant Undertakings". European Commission. February 24, 2009. Paragraph 71. Retrieved April 22, 2020.
  63. Sowell, Thomas (May 3, 1999). "Predatory prosecution".
  64. J. Gregory Sidak, Debunking Predatory Innovation, 83 COLUM. L. REV. 1121, 1121 (1983).
  65. Maury Klein. The Life and Legend of Jay Gould.
  66. Harold Demsetz (October 14, 1997). The Economics of the Business Firm: Seven Critical Commentaries. Cambridge University Press. p. 147. ISBN 9780521588652 via Google Books.
  67. R. Perman. "Chapter 7. Monopoly and barriers to entry". MBM Business economic notes.
  68. Bork, Robert (1993). The Antitrust Paradox: A Policy At War With Itself. Simon & Schuster. p. 148. ISBN 0029044561.
  69. Case 209/10, Post Danmark A/S v Konkurrencerådet [2012] EU:C:2012:172, para 22
  70. "DG Competition Discussion Paper on the Application of Article 82 of the Treaty to Exclusionary Abuses" (PDF). Brussels: European Commission. 2005. Paragraph 130. Retrieved April 22, 2020.
  71. "DG Competition Discussion Paper on the Application of Article 82 of the Treaty to Exclusionary Abuses" (PDF). Brussels: European Commission. 2005. Paragraph 131. Retrieved April 22, 2020.
  72. "DG Competition Discussion Paper on the Application of Article 82 of the Treaty to Exclusionary Abuses" (PDF). Brussels: European Commission. 2005. Paragraph 133. Retrieved April 22, 2020.
  73. Case 62/86, AKZO Chemie BV v Commission of the European Communities [1991] ECR I-03359, para 10
  74. Case 333/94 P, Tetra Pak International SA v Commission of the European Communities [1996] ECR I-5951, para 52
  75. Wanadoo Interactive (Case COMP/38.233) Commission decision of 16 July 2003, para 409
  76. Wanadoo Interactive (Case COMP/38.233) Commission decision of 16 July 2003, para 257
  77. Target matches WalMart's drug cuts; state law limits discounts, Associated Press, September 29, 2007, archived from the original on 2009-04-26, retrieved 2009-03-16
  78. Edmund L. Andrews (September 9, 2000), "Germany Says Wal-Mart Must Raise Prices", New York Times, retrieved 2009-03-16
  79. Victoria Shannon (January 14, 2008), Amazon.com is challenging French competition law, International Herald Tribune, archived from the original on 2008-01-15, retrieved 2009-03-16
  80. "Amazon snubs French free delivery ban with one-cent charge". France 24. July 11, 2014. Retrieved October 14, 2017.
  81. Areeda, Phillip E; Hovenkamp, Herbert (2002), Antitrust Law (2nd ed.), pp. 723–745
  82. Cabral, Luis M. B. (2000), Introduction to Industrial Organisation, MIT Press, p. 269
  83. Jones, Alison & Sufrin, Brenda (2007), EC Competition Law (3rd ed.), OUP, pp. 443–473
  84. McGee, John (April 1958), "Predatory Price Cutting: The Standard Oil (N.J.) Case", Journal of Law and Economics, 1: 137–169, doi:10.1086/466547
  85. https://www.wsj.com/articles/amazon-competition-shopify-wayfair-allbirds-antitrust-11608235127

EU Primary Sources Cited

  • Article 102 TFEU
  • ECS/AKZO (IV/30.698) Commission decision of 14 December 1985
  • Case 202/07 P, France Télécom SA v Commission of the European Communities [2009] ECR I-2369
  • Case 85/76, Hoffmann-La Roche & Co. AG v Commission of the European Communities [1979] ECR II-00461
  • Case 209/10, Post Danmark A/S v Konkurrencerådet [2012] EU:C:2012:172Case 333/94 P, Tetra Pak International SA v Commission of the European Communities [1996] ECR I-5951
  • Case 62/86, AKZO Chemie BV v Commission of the European Communities [1991] ECR I-03359
  • Case C-23/14, Post Danmark A/S v Konkurrencerådet EU:C:2015:651
  • Wanadoo Interactive (Case COMP/38.233) Commission decision of 16 July 2003

Works Cited

This article is issued from Wikipedia. The text is licensed under Creative Commons - Attribution - Sharealike. Additional terms may apply for the media files.