Productive efficiency

Productive efficiency (or production efficiency) is a situation in which the economy or an economic system (e.g., a firm, a bank, a hospital, an industry, a country, etc.) could not produce any more of one good without sacrificing production of another good and without improving the production technology.[1] In other words, productive efficiency occurs when a good or a service is produced at the lowest possible cost. In simple terms, the concept is illustrated on a production possibility frontier (PPF), where all points on the curve are points of productive efficiency.[2] An equilibrium may be productively efficient without being allocatively efficient i.e. it may result in a distribution of goods where social welfare is not maximized. It is one type of economic efficiency.

An example PPF: points B, C and D are all productively efficient, but an economy at A would not be, because D involves more production of both goods. Point X cannot be achieved.
Productive efficiency occurs under competitive equilibrium at the minimum of average total cost for each good, such as the one shown here.

Productive efficiency of an industry requires that all firms operate using best-practice technological and managerial processes and that there is no further reallocation that bring more output with the same inputs and the same production technology. By improving these processes, an economy or business can extend its production possibility frontier outward, so that efficient production yields more output than previously.

Productive inefficiency, with the economy operating below its production possibilities frontier, can occur because the productive inputs physical capital and labor are underutilized—that is, some capital or labor is left sitting idle—or because these inputs are allocated in inappropriate combinations to the different industries that use them.

In long-run equilibrium for perfectly competitive markets, productive efficiency occurs at the base of the average total cost curvei.e. where marginal cost equals average total costfor each good.

Due to the nature and culture of monopolistic companies, they may not be productively efficient because of X-inefficiency, whereby companies operating in a monopoly have less of an incentive to maximize output due to lack of competition. However, due to economies of scale it can be possible for the profit-maximizing level of output of monopolistic companies to occur with a lower price to the consumer than perfectly competitive companies.

Many theoretical measures of production efficiency have been proposed in the literature as well as many approaches to estimate them. The most popular measures of efficiency include Farrell measure[3] (also known as Debreu-Farrell measure, since Debrreu (1951) has similar ideas[4]). This measure is also the reciprocal of the Shephard's distance function.[5] These can be defined with either the input orientation (fix outputs and measure maximal possible reduction in inputs) or the output orientation (fix inputs and measure maximal possible expansion in outputs). A generalisation of these is the so-called Directional Distance Function, where one can select any direction (or orientation) for measuring the production efficiency. The most popular for estimating production efficiency are Data Envelopment Analysis[6] and Stochastic Frontier Analysis,[7] among other methods. (E.g., see the recent book by Sickles and Zelenyuk (2019) for comprehensive coverage of the theory and related estimation and many references therein.)[8]

References

  1. Sickles, R., & Zelenyuk, V. (2019). Measurement of Productivity and Efficiency: Theory and Practice. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. doi:10.1017/9781139565981
  2. Standish, Barry (1997). Economics: Principles and Practice. South Africa: Pearson Education. pp. 13–15. ISBN 978-1-86891-069-4.
  3. Farrell, M. J. (1957). The measurement of productive efficiency. Jornal of the Royal Statistical Society. Series A (General), 120(3):253–290.
  4. Debreu, G. (1951). The coefficient of resource utilization. Econometrica, 19(3):273–292.
  5. Shephard, R. W. (1953). Cost and Production Functions. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
  6. Charnes, A., Cooper, W., and Rhodes, E. (1978). Measuring the efficiency of decision making units. European Journal of Operational Research, 2(6):429–444.
  7. Aigner, D. J., Lovell, C. A. K. & Schmidt, P. (1977), ‘Formulation and estimation of stochastic frontier production functions’, Journal of Econometrics 6(1), 21–37.
  8. Sickles, R., & Zelenyuk, V. (2019). Measurement of Productivity and Efficiency: Theory and Practice. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. doi:10.1017/9781139565981
This article is issued from Wikipedia. The text is licensed under Creative Commons - Attribution - Sharealike. Additional terms may apply for the media files.