Marshallian demand function

In microeconomics, a consumer's Marshallian demand function (named after Alfred Marshall) specifies what the consumer would buy in each price and income or wealth situation, assuming it perfectly solves the utility maximization problem. Marshallian demand is sometimes called Walrasian demand (named after Léon Walras) or uncompensated demand function instead, because the original Marshallian analysis refused wealth effects.

According to the utility maximization problem, there are L commodities with price vector p and choosable quantity vector x. The consumer has income I, and hence a budget set of affordable packages

where is the inner product of the price and quantity vectors. The consumer has a utility function

The consumer's Marshallian demand correspondence is defined to be

Uniqueness

is called a correspondence because in general it may be set-valued - there may be several different bundles that attain the same maximum utility. In some cases, there is a unique utility-maximizing bundle for each price and income situation; then, is a function and it is called the Marshallian demand function.

If the consumer has strictly convex preferences and the prices of all goods are strictly positive, then there is a unique utility-maximizing bundle.[1]:156 To prove this, suppose, by contradiction, that there are two different bundles, and , that maximize the utility. Then and are equally preferred. By definition of strict convexity, the mixed bundle is strictly better than . But this contradicts the optimality of .

Continuity

The maximum theorem implies that if:

  • The utility function is continuous with respect to ,
  • The correspondence is non-empty, compact-valued, and continuous with respect to ,

then is an upper-semicontinuous correspondence. Moreover, if is unique, then it is a continuous function of and .[1]:156,506

Combining with the previous subsection, if the consumer has strictly convex preferences, then the Marshallian demand is unique and continuous. In contrast, if the preferences are not convex, then the Marshallian demand may be non-unique and non-continuous.

Homogeneity

The Marshallian demand correspondence is a homogeneous function with degree 0. This means that for every constant

This is intuitively clear. Suppose and are measured in dollars. When , and are exactly the same quantities measured in cents. Obviously, changing the unit of measurement should not affect the demand.

Examples

In the following examples, there are two commodities, 1 and 2.

1. The utility function has the Cobb–Douglas form:

The constrained optimization leads to the Marshallian demand function:

2. The utility function is a CES utility function:

Then

In both cases, the preferences are strictly convex, the demand is unique and the demand function is continuous.

3. The utility function has the linear form:

The utility function is only weakly convex, and indeed the demand is not unique: when , the consumer may divide his income in arbitrary ratios between product types 1 and 2 and get the same utility.

4. The utility function exhibits a non-diminishing marginal rate of substitution:

The utility function is not concave, and indeed the demand is not continuous: when , the consumer demands only product 1, and when , the consumer demands only product 2 (when the demand correspondence contains two distinct bundles: either buy only product 1 or buy only product 2).

See also

References

  • Mas-Colell, Andreu; Whinston, Michael & Green, Jerry (1995). Microeconomic Theory. Oxford: Oxford University Press. ISBN 0-19-507340-1.
  • Nicholson, Walter (1978). Microeconomic Theory (Second ed.). Hinsdale: Dryden Press. pp. 90–93. ISBN 0-03-020831-9.
  1. Varian, Hal (1992). Microeconomic Analysis (Third ed.). New York: Norton. ISBN 0-393-95735-7.
This article is issued from Wikipedia. The text is licensed under Creative Commons - Attribution - Sharealike. Additional terms may apply for the media files.