Daron Acemoglu

Kamer Daron Acemoğlu (Turkish: [daˈɾon aˈdʒemoːɫu]; born September 3, 1967) is a Turkish-born Armenian-American economist who has taught at the Massachusetts Institute of Technology (MIT) since 1993. He is currently the Elizabeth and James Killian Professor of Economics at MIT. He was named Institute Professor in 2019.

Daron Acemoglu
Acemoglu in 2016
Born
Kamer Daron Acemoğlu

(1967-09-03) September 3, 1967
Istanbul, Turkey
CitizenshipTurkey and United States
Spouse(s)Asu Ozdaglar
Institution
FieldPolitical economy, Economic growth, Labour economics
School or
tradition
New institutional economics
Alma mater
Doctoral
advisor
Kevin W. S. Roberts
Doctoral
students
Robert ShimerMark AguiarPol AntràsGabriel CarrollMelissa DellBenjamin Jones
InfluencesJoel MokyrKenneth SokoloffDouglass NorthSeymour Martin LipsetBarrington Moore
Awards

Born to Armenian parents in Istanbul, Acemoglu completed his MSc and then PhD at the London School of Economics (LSE) at 25. He lectured at LSE for a year before joining the MIT. He was awarded the John Bates Clark Medal in 2005. Acemoglu is best known for his work on political economy. He has authored hundreds of papers, many of which are co-authored with his long-time collaborators Simon Johnson and James A. Robinson. With Robinson, he authored Economic Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy (2006) and Why Nations Fail (2012). The latter, an influential book on the role that institutions play in shaping nations' economic outcomes, prompted wide scholarly and media commentary. Described as a centrist, he believes in a regulated market economy. He regularly comments on political issues, economic inequality, and a variety of specific policies.

Acemoglu ranked third, behind Paul Krugman and Greg Mankiw, in the list of "Favorite Living Economists Under Age 60" in a 2011 survey among American economists. In 2015 he was named the most cited economist of the past 10 years per Research Papers in Economics (RePEc) data.

Life

Kamer Daron Acemoğlu[1][2][lower-alpha 1] was born in Istanbul, Turkey to Armenian parents[5][6] on September 3, 1967.[7] He is the only child of Kevork Acemoglu (1938−1988), a commercial lawyer and lecturer at Istanbul University, and Irma (d. 1991), principal of Aramyan Uncuyan, an Armenian school in the Kadıköy district.[8][9][10] He attended an Armenian school in Istanbul[11] and graduated from Galatasaray High School in 1986.[12] He became interested in politics and economics as a teenager.[10] He earned his BA in economics at the University of York in 1989, his MSc in econometrics and mathematical economics and PhD in economics from the London School of Economics (LSE), in 1990 and 1992 respectively.[13] His doctoral thesis was titled "Essays in Microfoundations of Macroeconomics: Contracts and Economic Performance."[7][2] His doctoral advisor was Kevin W. S. Roberts.[14] James Malcomson, one of his doctoral examiners at the LSE, said that even the weakest three of the seven chapters of his thesis were "more than sufficient for the award of a PhD."[15]

Arnold Kling called him a wunderkind due to his age of receiving a PhD; he became a Doctor at 25.[16]

Acemoglu is a naturalized US citizen.[17] He is fluent in English and Turkish.[18] He is married to Asuman "Asu" Ozdağlar, a professor of Electrical Engineering and Computer Science at Massachusetts Institute of Technology (MIT)[10][19] and daughter of İsmail Özdağlar, a former Turkish government minister.[20] Together they have authored several articles.[21][22] As of 2015, they live in Newton, Massachusetts with their two sons (Arda and Aras).[23]

Academic career

Acemoglu in 2009
Acemoglu in his office, January 2020

Acemoglu was a lecturer in economics at the LSE from 1992 to 1993. He began lecturing at the MIT in 1993, when he was appointed Assistant Professor of Economics. He was granted a tenure at MIT in 1998,[24] and promoted to full professor in 2000.[25] In 2004 he became Charles P. Kindleberger Professor of Applied Economics. Since 2010 Acemoglu has been the Elizabeth and James Killian Professor of Economics at MIT.[7] In July 2019 he was named Institute Professor, the highest faculty honor at MIT.[26]

As of mid-2019 he has had over 60 PhD students.[26] Among his doctoral students are Robert Shimer, Mark Aguiar, Pol Antràs, and Gabriel Carroll.[14]

In 2014 he made $841,380, making him one of the top earners at MIT.[27]

He is a fellow of the United States National Academy of Sciences, American Academy of Arts and Sciences, Econometric Society, European Economic Association, and other learned societies.[13] He is a Research Associate at the National Bureau of Economic Research,[28] and a Senior Fellow at the Canadian Institute for Advanced Research.[29] He was the editor of Econometrica, an academic journal published by the Econometric Society, from 2011 to 2015.[30]

Acemoglu has authored hundreds of academic papers.[31] He noted that most of his research has been "motivated by trying to understand the sources of poverty."[17] His research includes a wide range of topics, including political economy, human capital theory, growth theory, economic development, innovation, labor economics,[13][32] income and wage inequality, network economics, etc.[33] He noted in 2011 that most his research of the past 15 years concerned with what can be broadly called political economy.[34] He has made contribution to the labor economics field.[17]

Acemoglu has extensively collaborated with James A. Robinson, a British political scientist, since 1993.[24] Acemoglu has described it as a "very productive relationship." They have worked together on a number of articles and several books, most of which on the subject of growth and economic development.[17] The two have also extensively collaborated with economist Simon Johnson.[35]

Publications

For a selected bibliography, see below

Economic Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy

Published by Cambridge University Press in 2006, Economic Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy by Acemoglu and Robinson analyzes the creation and consolidation of democratic societies. They argue that "democracy consolidates when elites do not have strong incentive to overthrow it. These processes depend on (1) the strength of civil society, (2) the structure of political institutions, (3) the nature of political and economic crises, (4) the level of economic inequality, (5) the structure of the economy, and (6) the form and extent of globalization."[36]

Romain Wacziarg praised the book and argued that its substantive contribution is the theoretical fusion of the Marxist dialectical materialism ("institutional change results from distributional struggles between two distinct social groups, a rich ruling class and a poor majority, each of whose interests are shaped primarily by economic forces") and the ideas of Barry Weingast and Douglass North, who argued that "institutional reform can be a way for the elite to credibly commit to future policies by delegating their enactment to interests that will not wish to reverse them."[37] William Easterly called it "one of the most important contributions to the literature on the economics of democracy in a long time." Edward Glaeser described it as "enormously significant" work and a "great contribution to the field."[38]

Why Nations Fail was included in the Shortlist of the 2012 Financial Times Business Book of the Year Award.

Why Nations Fail

In their 2012 book, Why Nations Fail, Acemoglu and Robinson argue that economic growth at the forefront of technology requires political stability, which the Mayan civilization (to name only one) did not have,[39] and creative destruction. The latter cannot occur without institutional restraints on the granting of monopoly and oligopoly rights. They say that the industrial revolution began in Great Britain, because the English Bill of Rights 1689 created such restraints. For example, a steam boat built in 1705 by Denis Papin was demolished by a boatmen guild in Münden, Germany. Papin went to London, where several of his papers were published by the Royal Society. Thomas Newcomen extended Papin's work into a steam engines in 1712, and became a commercial success, while Papin died in 1713 and was buried in an unmarked pauper's grave.[40]

Acemoglu and Robinson insist that "development differences across countries are exclusively due to differences in political and economic institutions, and reject other theories that attribute some of the differences to culture, weather, geography or lack of knowledge about the best policies and practices."[41] For example, "Soviet Russia generated rapid growth as it caught up rapidly with some of the advanced technologies in the world [but] was running out of steam by the 1970s" because of a lack of creative destruction.[42]

The book was written for the general audience.[41] It was widely discussed by political analysts and commentators.[43][44][45][46] Warren Bass wrote of it in The Washington Post: "bracing, garrulous, wildly ambitious and ultimately hopeful. It may, in fact, be a bit of a masterpiece."[47]

Clive Crook wrote in Bloomberg News that the book deserves most of the "lavish praise" it received.[48] In his review in Foreign Affairs Jeffrey Sachs criticized Acemoglu and Robinson for systematically ignoring factors such as domestic politics, geopolitics, technological discoveries, and natural resources. He also argued that the book's appeal was based on readers' desire to hear that "Western democracy pays off not only politically but also economically."[49] Bill Gates called the book a "major disappointment" and characterized the authors' analysis as "vague and simplistic."[50] Ryan Avent, an editor at The Economist, responded that "Acemoglu and Robinson might not be entirely right about why nations succeed or fail. But at least they're engaged with the right problem."[51]

Views

Acemoglu is a follower of new institutional economics.[52][53][54] Among economists who have influenced him are Joel Mokyr and Kenneth Sokoloff,[55] Douglass North,[56] Seymour Martin Lipset,[57] Barrington Moore.[57]

Journalists and economists describe him as a centrist.[lower-alpha 2] Paul Abrams noted that Why Nations Fail was well received by both liberal and conservative economists.[61] Acemoglu's and Robinson's long-time collaborator Simon Johnson suggests that their "point is not just about how things may become awful when the government goes off track (a right-wing point). They are also more deeply concerned about how powerful people fight to grab control of the state and otherwise compete to exert influence over the rest of society (a left-wing perspective)."[35]

Acemoglu has praised the successes of the Progressive Era, and argued in favor of its replication.[62] Johnson notes that for Acemoglu and Robinson a balance between the government and large private businesses is essential.[35] Acemoglu argues that the market economy is the only system that creates prosperity. He believes in finding an appropriate balance between "incentivizing creativity, hard work and risk-taking and creating the essential public services, social safety nets and equality of opportunity."[63] For Acemoglu, markets work only with regulations and predictable laws and that all markets are regulated to some extent; it is only a matter of degree.[24] He suggests that free markets are not unregulated markets.[64] While he believes that property rights and private property are absolutely essential for prosperity, he has stated that "these things are very political and the politics shouldn’t be one-sided."[65]

Wall Street

In September 2008 Acemoglu signed a petition condemning the Bush administration's bailout plan of the U.S. financial system.[66] As the main cause of the 2008 financial crisis he stated that policy makers were "lured by ideological notions derived from Ayn Rand’s novels rather than economic theory" and opined that "In hindsight, we should not be surprised that unregulated profit-seeking individuals have taken risks from which they benefit and others lose."[64] In an early analysis of the Great Recession, Acemoglu wrote: "When channeled into profit-maximizing, competitive, and innovative behavior under the auspices of sound laws and regulations, greed can act as the engine of innovation and economic growth. But when unchecked by the appropriate institutions and regulations, it will degenerate into rent-seeking, corruption, and crime."[24] He suggests that progressive tax may reduce the rent-seeking activities of those at the top of the income bracket.[65] According to him the U.S. financial system has become increasingly concentrated due its high profitability and investment in high-risk assets. He voices doubt about the effectiveness of the Dodd–Frank Act in preventing the next financial collapse if the financial system continues on its current trajectory, especially what he calls the bonus culture.[34] He argues that the heavy overrepresentation from the financial sector in the top 1% "has been an outcome of the political processes that have removed all of the regulations in finance, and so created the platform for 40 percent of U.S. corporate profits to be in the financial sector."[34] He argues that a platform, particularly in Wall Street, has been created "where the ambition and greed of people, often men, has been channeled in a very anti-social, selfish and socially destructive direction."[65]

Inequality

Acemoglu has voiced concerns regarding the increasing inequality in the United States, which, he argues, turns into political inequality which, in turn, undermines the inclusiveness of American institutions.[44] In a 2012 interview Acemoglu identified societal polarization, caused by economic inequality, as the biggest problem for the United States. He argues that the political system is dominated by the wealthy, while the voices of ordinary Americans are not heard.[67] According to him "democracy ceases to function because some people have so much money they command greater power."[60] He and Robinson wrote in 2012 that "those who are further empowered politically will use this to gain a greater economic advantage by stacking the cards in their favor and increasing economic inequality yet further — a quintessential vicious circle."[68] He states that he is comfortable with economic inequality which comes through different social contributions as it is a "price that we pay for providing incentives for people to contribute to prosperity." However, high levels of inequality create problems as the rich who control significant portions of the societal resources use them to create an "unequal distribution of political power."[65] He sees the solution in increasing social mobility by "providing an opportunity for the bottom to become rich, not forcing the rich to become poor."[60]

He has praised the American tradition of vibrant protest movements dating back to Populists and Progressives.[69] He has also praised Occupy Wall Street for "putting the question of inequality on the agenda, but also for actually standing up for political equality."[68] He notes that Occupy Wall Street brought the 1% to the attention of the wider public, academic attention was brought by Tony Atkinson, Thomas Piketty, and Emmanuel Saez.[65]

Social programs and policies

Acemoglu is in favor of raising and indexing the minimum wage.[70] He argues that minimum wages and unemployment benefits "shift the composition of employment toward high-wage jobs. Because the composition of jobs in the laissez-faire equilibrium is inefficiently biased toward low-wage jobs, these labor market regulations increase average labor productivity and may improve welfare."[71] Furthermore, he argues that "minimum wages can increase training of affected workers, by inducing firms to train their unskilled employees."[72]

Acemoglu believes that universal basic income is "expensive and not generous enough" and that a "more efficient and generous social safety net is needed."[73] He further called it a "flawed idea" and a "poorly designed policy." He instead advocates for a "guaranteed-income program would offer transfers only to individuals whose monthly income is below $1,000, thereby coming in at a mere fraction of a UBI’s cost." He calls for "universal health care, more generous unemployment benefits, better-designed retraining programs, and an expanded earned income tax credit (EITC)."[74]

Democracy and authoritarian regimes

Acemoglu et al. found that "democracy has a significant and robust positive effect on GDP" and suggest that "democratizations increase GDP per capita by about 20% in the long run."[75] They also found that "there is a significant and robust effect of democracy on tax revenues as a fraction of GDP, but no robust impact on inequality."[76]

According to Acemoglu the three obstacles for economic growth under authoritarian regimes are the tendency of authoritarian regimes to become more authoritarian, their tendency to use power to halt "Schumpeterian creative destruction, which is key to sustaining growth" and the instability and uncertainty caused by internal conflicts.[24] Authoritarian countries are, by definition, extractive.[77] He believes that Saudi Arabia would be like a poor African country without the oil, while the "only thing that is keeping [Russia] going is a big boom in natural resources and a clever handling of the media."[78]

He believes that China has managed to achieve significant economic growth because it "sort of picked up the low hanging fruit from the world technology frontier, but that sort of growth is not going to last until China goes to the next step, which is harnessing innovation," which he argues will be impossible "unless economic institutions become even more open and the extractive political institutions in China will be a barrier to that."[67] He and Robinson wrote for the HuffPost that the "limited rights [China] affords its citizens places major restrictions on the country’s longer-term possibilities for prosperity."[79]

Socialism, communism, and Marxism

Acemoglu argues that socialist countries have not been successful in creating prosperity.[63] He wrote that socialist regimes "from Cuba to the eastern bloc have been disastrous both for economic prosperity and individual freedom."[80] With Robinson, he argues that the Soviet Union and all of the other communist regimes were extractive from the beginning because of failure to provide economic incentives and concentrated political power in the "hands of a very narrow elite and backed it up with coercion and force."[81]

In a review written with Robinson, he argues that Thomas Piketty and Karl Marx are "led astray" due to their disregard for "the key forces shaping how an economy functions: the endogenous evolution of technology and of the institutions and the political equilibrium that influence not only technology but also how markets function and how the gains from various different economic arrangements are distributed."[82]

Social democracy and unions

In 2019 Acemoglu argued in favor of social democracy. He stated:[80]

[Social democracy, when practiced by competent governments] is a phenomenal success. Everywhere in the west is to some degree social democratic, but the extent of this varies. We owe our prosperity and freedom to social democracy. [...] [Social democracy] did not achieve these things by taxing and redistributing a lot. It achieved them by having labor institutions protecting workers, encouraging job creation and encouraging high wages.

Acemoglu also noted that the economists of US presidential candidate Bernie Sanders, who is a self-proclaimed advocate of social democracy, "don’t understand basic economics. They are not just dangerous, they are clueless."[80]

Acemoglu has argued that a "tradition of strong labor movement or social democratic party, by constraining the actions of the social planner, can act as a commitment device to egalitarianism, inducing an equilibrium in which the country in question becomes the beneficiary from the asymmetric world equilibrium."[83] According to Acemoglu and Robinson, unions, historically had a significant role in creating democracy, especially in western Europe, and maintaining a balance between political power of established business interests and political elites.[84]

Acemoglu and Philippe Aghion argued in 2001 that although deunionization in the US and UK since the 1980s is not the "underlying cause of the increase in inequality", it "amplifies the direct effect of skill-biased technical change by removing the wage compression imposed by unions."[85]

Nordic model

In a 2012 paper titled "Can't We All Be More Like Scandinavians?", co-written with Robinson and Thierry Verdier, he suggests that "the more 'cutthroat' American society that makes possible the more 'cuddly' Scandinavian societies based on a comprehensive social safety net, the welfare state and more limited inequality." They concluded that "all countries may want to be like the 'Scandinavians' with a more extensive safety net and a more egalitarian structure," however, if the United States, the "cutthroat [capitalism] leader", the economic growth of the entire world would be reduced.[83] He argued against the US adopting the Nordic model in a 2015 op-ed for The New York Times. He again argued, "If the US increased taxation to Denmark levels, it would reduce rewards for entrepreneurship, with negative consequences for growth and prosperity." He praised the Scandinavian experience in poverty reduction, creation of a level playing field for its citizens, and higher social mobility.[86] This was critiqued by Lane Kenworthy who argues that, empirically, the US's economic growth preceded the divergence in 'cutthroat' and 'cuddly' policies and there is no relationship between inequality and innovation for developed countries.[87]

Colonialism

"The Colonial Origins of Comparative Development", co-written by Acemoglu, Robinson, Simon Johnson in 2001 is, by far, his most cited work.[31] Graham Mallard described it as "excellent example of his work: an influential paper that has led to much debate."[25] They argue that Europeans set up extractive institutions in colonies where they did not settle, unlike in places where they did settle and that these institutions have persisted. They estimated that "differences in institutions explain approximately three-quarters of the income per capita differences across from former colonies."[88] Historical experience dominated by extractive institutions in these countries has created a vicious circle, which was exacerbated by the European colonization.[81]

Party politics

Acemoglu argued just before the 2016 presidential election that the Democratic Party "should seek a coalition that stands for the most vulnerable people in society" which, he believes, "could not stand by itself without the support of influential, well-off members of American society."[89]

Donald Trump

In an op-ed in Foreign Policy Acemoglu claimed President Donald Trump shared political goals and strategies of Hugo Chávez, Vladimir Putin, and Recep Tayyip Erdoğan such as "little respect for the rule of law or the independence of state institutions [...] a blurred vision of national and personal interests [...] little patience with criticism and a long-established strategy of rewarding loyalty, which can be seen in his high-level appointments to date. This is all topped by an unwavering belief in his abilities."[69] In a 2019 interview Acemoglu stated that he sees similarities between Trump and the Republican Party and the Nazis: "Surely, Trump and the Republicans are no Nazis. But they are exploiting the same political sentiment." He argues that Trump "poses a great risk to U.S. democracy," because he is "looking for a new order with elements of anti-liberalism, misinformation and a lax attitude to corruption. If he is re-elected next year, it will be the beginning of the end of American democracy."[90]

Specific policies

Acemoglu believes that nation-building by the West is no longer possible around the world because the West now lacks the resources and commitment that were present in post-World War II Germany and Japan and because countries where such work is required today (many in the Muslim- and Arab-majority countries) do not trust the West.[91] He views the U.S. war on drugs as a "total and very costly failure"[92] and supported the 2013 ballot referendum Colorado Amendment 64, a successful popular initiative that legalized the sale of recreational marijuana.[93] According to him "it is clear that public schools are failing and alternatives are necessary."[94] In a 2016 interview he opined that the US infrastructure is in a "pitiful state, with negative consequences for US economic growth."[95]

Turkey

In March 2011 Acemoglu was offered by Foreign Minister Ahmet Davutoğlu to become Turkey's permanent representative to the OECD in Paris, which he rejected in order to continue his academic career.[96][97][98][99] It was seen in Armenia as a politically motivated move to earn "political dividends" on Armenian issues.[100]

Acemoglu opined that the Republic of Turkey, formed in 1923 by Atatürk, "is very continuous with the Ottoman Empire." Although the shift from empire to republic brought some positive changes, he argues, the model was largely maintained by the reformers who took power, citing a persistent concentration of power and economic activity.[101] He suggests that the Republican period has been characterized by an unwillingness to accept ethnic minorities.[102] In 2014 Acemoglu condemned the widespread anti-Armenian rhetoric in Turkish textbooks, and demanded that the books be pulled from circulation.[9]

Acemoglu has criticized Recep Tayyip Erdoğan and his government for its authoritarian rule.[103] In a 2013 op-ed in The New York Times, following the crackdown of Gezi Park protests, Acemoglu wrote that "Even before the brutal suppression of the demonstrations, the belief that Turkey was on its way to becoming a mature democracy — a role model for the rest of the Middle East — had already become untenable."[104] In a May 2014 op-ed Foreign Affairs Acemoglu wrote that the drift from democracy by Erdogan is lamentable, but an "almost predictable, stage of Turkey’s democratic transition."[105] In the late 2010s, Acemoglu often criticized Turkey's economic policies and consequently became popular with the opposition.[106]

Armenia

Acemoglu, an ethnic Armenian, stated in a 2015 interview with the Armenian service of Voice of America, that he has always been interested in economic, political, and social developments in Armenia.[11] Talking via video, Acemoglu partook in the Armenian Economic Association's annual conference in October 2013 held at the Yerevan State University, during which he argued that Armenia's problem is political, and not geographic, cultural, or geopolitical. He called for the Armenian government to be "more responsive to the wishes of its citizens so that through that political process Armenia ceases to be an oligarchy."[107] In a September 2016 conference in Toronto Acemoglu criticized the Armenian diaspora for legitimizing the successive governments in Armenia, especially when the rights of its citizens are violated and a wrong economic and political line is being followed for the country.[108] In an April 2017 conference held by the USC Institute of Armenian Studies Acemoglu stated while "Armenia could have looked much more like the Czech Republic or Estonia and what we got instead is a country that looks much more like Azerbaijan or Uzbekistan, which is a real shame." He suggested that in the immediate post-Soviet years Armenia was "stronger and it's been getting worse and worse." He criticized the level of corruption of the government, which has systematically closed the political system.[109]

Following the 2018 Armenian revolution, opposition leader-turned-Prime Minister Nikol Pashinyan wrote on his Facebook page that Acemoglu told him that he is ready to help Armenia to "restore and develop" its economy.[110][111] Pashinyan and Acemoglu talked via the internet in June 2018.[112] Acemoglu met with Deputy Prime Minister Tigran Avinyan in Boston in July 2019.[113][114]

Other countries

Acemoglu predicted that the UK-EU deal is "likely to be similar to the status quo ante" and the Brexit referendum will not have a significant impact on the UK's real per-capita income.[115]

Acemoglu argued that the Greek government-debt crisis was caused by the "terrible state of Greek institutions, and the clientelistic nature of its politics" and that the country's problems are "political not just macroeconomic." He identified lack of political integration within the EU as Greece's problem and that "the only way forward for Europe is to have greater fiscal and banking integration or to abandon monetary integration." He criticized the policies of Syriza and stated that it is "unclear whether default will help."[116][117] On the 2015 bailout referendum, Acemoglu argued that "Greece may be better off without the euro but political risks, especially with current government, would be great, so a 'no' [vote] is very risky."[118]

In an op-ed for The Globe and Mail following the 2014 Ukrainian revolution, Acemoglu advocated Ukraine "to break with its past as quickly as possible. It needs to move away from Russia, politically and economically, even if that means an end to the natural-gas subsidies Russia has used to keep it in the position of a client state. Even more important is for Ukraine’s leaders to spread political power and economic benefits to the maximum number of its people, including Russian speakers."[119]

Recognition

According to data collected by Research Papers in Economics (RePEc), Acemoglu was the most cited economist of the decade leading to 2015.[6][9][120] According to Google Scholar his works (including co-authored works) have been cited nearly 135,800 times as of July 2019.[31] He was listed 88th in Foreign Policy's 2010 list of Top 100 Global Thinkers "for showing that freedom is about more than markets."[121] In a 2011 survey of 299 economics professors in the U.S. Acemoglu ranked third, behind Paul Krugman and Greg Mankiw, in the list of "Favorite Living Economists Under Age 60".[122]

MIT President L. Rafael Reif stated that Acemoglu "embodies the essence of MIT: boldness, rigor and real-world impact."[26] Francis Fukuyama has described Acemoglu and his long-time collaborator James A. Robinson as "two of the world's leading experts on development."[123] Clement Douglas wrote in the Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis publication that the "scope, depth and sheer volume of [his] scholarship are nothing short of breathtaking, verging on implausible."[34] Angus Deaton called him a "young superstar" and noted that Acemoglu is "a very good example of the way things ought to be going, which is you do history but you know enough mathematics to be able to model it too."[124] Robert Shimer wrote, "His unparalleled combination of originality, thoroughness, and prolificacy has propelled him to the frontier of each field that he has explored."[15] Adam Davidson noted in 2012, the year Why Nations Fail was published, that Acemoglu "is about as hot as economists get."[125] Michael Mandel identified him in 2009 as a leader of innovation economics.[126]

Awards

Economics awards
State orders and awards
Honorary degrees

Acemoglu has been awarded honorary degrees from the following universities: Utrecht University (2008),[34] Bosporus University (2011), Bilkent University (2015),[136] University of Bath (2017),[137] ENS Paris-Saclay (2017), London Business School (2018), Boğaziçi University, and the University of Athens.[13]

Other

Selected publications

Books

  • Acemoglu, Daron; Robinson, James A. (2006). Economic Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy. Cambridge University Press. ISBN 9780521855266.
  • Acemoglu, Daron (2008). Introduction to Modern Economic Growth. Princeton University Press. ISBN 9781400835775.
  • Acemoglu, Daron; Robinson, James A. (2012). Why Nations Fail. Crown Business. ISBN 978-0307719218.
  • Acemoglu, Daron; Laibson, David and List, John (2014). Principles of Economics, Pearson, New York.
  • Acemoglu, Daron; Robinson, James A. (2019). The Narrow Corridor: States, Societies, and the Fate of Liberty. Penguin Press. ISBN 978-0735224384. Description, arrow-searchable preview, & reviewers' comments (at bottom).

References

Notes
  1. Western Armenian: Տարօն Աճէմօղլու.[3][4] Acemoğlu is the Turkified version of the Armenian last name Աճէմեան, Ajemian. Its root derives from the Arabic term ajam, used for non-Arabs, especially Persians. Most Armenians changed their last names due to the 1934 Surname Law. His first name is the Western Armenian version of Taron, a male given name from a historic region.
  2. "... the middle-of-the-roaders Daron Acemoglu and James Robinson ..."[58]
    "Daron Acemoglu, a more centrist economist at MIT ..."[59]
    "... Acemoglu, who aligns more with the center than with the populists."[60]
Citations
  1. "Arşaluys Acemoğlu". Milliyet (in Turkish). 14 May 1985. Archived from the original on 13 October 2017. ...Kevork ve İrma Acemoğulları...Kamer Daron Acemoğlu...
  2. Acemoglu, Kamer Daron (1992). "Essays in microfoundations of macroeconomics : contracts and macroeconomic performance". British Library Board. Archived from the original on 13 October 2017.
  3. "Աճեմօղլու արաջին դիրքի վրայ". Jamanak (in Armenian). 31 July 2015.
  4. "Տարօն Աճէմօղլու Ստացաւ "Կալաթասարայ" Մրցանակը". Asbarez (in Armenian). 28 June 2012.
  5. Sorman, Guy (2013). Economics Does Not Lie: A Defense of the Free Market in a Time of Crisis. Encounter Books. p. 31. ISBN 978-1594032547. ...Daron Acemoğlu, an Armenian from Turkey...
  6. "Istanbul-born MIT professor named world's most influential economist". Hürriyet Daily News. 31 July 2015. (PDF version)
  7. "Curriculum Vitae Daron Acemoglu". economics.mit.edu. Massachusetts Institute of Technology. (archived)
  8. "Daron Acemoğlu, dünyanın en önemli 10 iktisatçısından biri". Agos (in Turkish). 28 October 2013. Archived from the original on 8 September 2017.
  9. "Daron Acemoglu Named Most Influential Economist". Armenian Weekly. 7 August 2015. (archived PDF)
  10. Gavin, Robert (15 June 2005). "MIT professor named top economist under 40". The Boston Globe. (archived)
  11. Tarjimanyan, Arman (2 April 2015). "Տարոն Աճեմօղլու. "Արտագաղթը սարսափելի վտանգ է Հայաստանի համար"". azatutyun.am (in Armenian). Radio Free Europe/Radio Liberty Armenian Service.
  12. "Prominent Armenian economist wins Galatasaray award". PanARMENIAN.Net. 2 December 2011.
  13. "Faculty & Research: Daron Acemoglu". mit.edu. Archived from the original on 9 September 2017.
  14. "Daron Kamer Acemoglu". genealogy.ams.org. Mathematics Genealogy Project (Department of Mathematics, North Dakota State University). Archived from the original on 2017-11-08.CS1 maint: bot: original URL status unknown (link)
  15. Shimer 2007, p. 191.
  16. Kling, Arnold (3 October 2007), Acemoglu on Growth, Library of Economics and Liberty
  17. "Daron Acemoglu". BBVA Foundation Frontiers of Knowledge Award. 2016. Archived from the original on 2017-11-04. (, )
  18. Examples of Acemoglu speaking Turkish:
  19. Hardesty, Larry (18 June 2013). "Gaming the System". MIT Technology Review. ...Ozdaglar and her husband, the MIT economist Daron Acemoglu...
  20. "Manisalı Eski Bakanın Kızı, Dünyanın En İyi Mühendisi Seçildi". Haberler.com (in Turkish). 8 April 2008.
  21. "Asuman Ozdaglar". National Bureau of Economic Research.
  22. "Asuman Ozdaglar". Google Scholar.
  23. "Political Institutions and Comparative Development". nber.org. National Bureau of Economic Research. Archived from the original on 15 September 2017.
  24. Willson, Simon (March 2010). "Breacher of the Peace". Finance & Development. 47 (1): 1–4. (PDF version)
  25. Mallard, Graham (2012). The Economics Companion. Palgrave Macmillan. p. 265. ISBN 9780230356450.
  26. Dizikes, Peter (July 10, 2019). "Daron Acemoglu named Institute Professor". news.mit.edu. MIT News Office. Archived from the original on 11 July 2019.
  27. Bingham, Emma (2 June 2016). "MIT's highest pay goes to administrators, MITIMCo leadership". The Tech. Archived from the original on 17 September 2017.CS1 maint: bot: original URL status unknown (link)
  28. "Daron Acemoglu". nber.org. National Bureau of Economic Research.
  29. "Daron Acemoglu". cifar.ca.
  30. "Past Editors and Co-editors of Econometrica". econometricsociety.org. Econometric Society. Archived from the original on 2016-11-30.CS1 maint: bot: original URL status unknown (link)
  31. "Daron Acemoglu". Google Scholar.
  32. Shimer 2007, pp. 199–200.
  33. "Daron Acemoglu". cifar.ca. Canadian Institute for Advanced Research.
  34. Clement, Douglas (27 September 2011). "Interview with Daron Acemoglu". Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis. (archived)
  35. Johnson, Simon (8 March 2012). "The Koch Brothers, the Cato Institute and Why Nations Fail". The New York Times.
  36. "Economic Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy". Cambridge University Press.
  37. Wacziarg, Romain (15 September 2006). "Determinants of Democratization". Science. 313 (5793): 1576–1577. doi:10.1126/science.1131936. JSTOR 20031295. S2CID 154213515.
  38. Drazen, Allan (February 2007). "Review: Four Reviews of "Economic Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy"". The Economic Journal. 117 (517): F162–F183. doi:10.1111/j.1468-0297.2007.02031_1.x. JSTOR 4625479.
  39. e.g., p. 143
  40. esp. pp. 202-203.
  41. Radelet, Steven (12 October 2012). "Why Nations Fail by Daron Acemoglu and James A. Robinson". United States Agency for International Development. Archived from the original on 16 September 2017.
  42. p. 150.
  43. "Creating economic wealth: The big why". The Economist.
  44. Friedman, Thomas L. (31 March 2012). "Why Nations Fail". The New York Times.
  45. Collier, Paul (11 March 2012). "Why Nations Fail by Daron Acemoğlu and James Robinson – review". The Guardian.
  46. Hunter, Janet (31 August 2012). "Book Review: Why Nations Fail: the Origins of Power, Prosperity, and Poverty by Daron Acemoglu & James A Robinson". London School of Economics.
  47. Bass, Warren (20 April 2012). "Book review: 'Why Nations Fail,' by Daron Acemoglu and James A. Robinson". The Washington Post.
  48. Crook, Clive (4 April 2012). "'Why Nations Fail' Is Not Quite as Good as They Say". Bloomberg News. Archived from the original on 27 October 2017.CS1 maint: bot: original URL status unknown (link)
  49. Sachs, Jeffrey (2012). "Government, Geography, and Growth: The True Drivers of Economic Development". Foreign Affairs. 91 (5): 142–150. JSTOR 41720868.
  50. Gates, Bill (26 February 2013). "Good Ideas, but Missing Analysis". gatesnotes.com. Archived from the original on 17 October 2017.
  51. R.A. (6 March 2013). "Institutions matter, a lot". The Economist.
  52. Dzionek-Kozłowska, Joanna; Matera, Rafał (October 2015). "New Institutional Economics' Perspective on Wealth and Poverty of Nations. Concise Review and General Remarks on Acemoglu and James A. Robinson's Concept". Annals of the Alexandru Ioan Cuza University – Economics. 62 (1): 11–18. doi:10.1515/aicue-2015-0032.
  53. Keefer, Philip; Knack, Stephen (2005). "Social capital, social norms and the New Institutional Economics". Handbook of New Institutional Economics. pp. 700–725.
  54. "Introductory Reading List: New Institutional Economics". coase.org. Ronald Coase Institute. Archived from the original on 25 December 2019. Retrieved 11 January 2020.
  55. Why Nations Fail, "Acknowledgments", p. 209 "Two people played a particularly significant role in shaping our views and encouraging our research, and we would like to take this opportunity to express our intellectual debt and our sincere gratitude to them: Joel Mokyr, and Ken Sokoloff...
  56. Wilkinson, Will (10 May 2016). "The Great Enrochment and Social Justice". Niskanen Center. Douglass North and his followers, such as Daron Acemoglu and James Robinson...
  57. Dewan, Torun; Shepsle, Kenneth A. (July 2008). "Recent Economic Perspectives on Political Economy, Part II". British Journal of Political Science. 38 (3): 543–564. doi:10.1017/S0007123408000276. PMC 3630075. PMID 23606754. ...Seymour Martin Lipset and Barrington Moore, for example, have clearly influenced Acemoglu and Robinson and other contributors to the literature on redistribution...
  58. McCloskey, Deirdre (January 2015). "It was ideas and ideologies, not interests or institutions, which changed in Northwestern Europe, 1600–1848". Journal of Evolutionary Economics. 25 (1): 57. doi:10.1007/s00191-015-0392-x. S2CID 154238344.
  59. Edsall, Thomas B. (28 January 2014). "Capitalism vs. Democracy". The New York Times.
  60. Keller, Bill (22 December 2013). "Inequality for Dummies". The New York Times.
  61. Abrams, Paul (5 June 2012). "Romney-Ryan's Why Nations Fail Economy vs. Obama's Built to Last Economy". HuffPost.
  62. Acemoglu, Daron; Johnson, Simon (15 August 2017). "It's Time to Found a New Republic". Foreign Policy.
  63. "Is democratic socialism the right path for America?". CNN. 28 October 2015. (archived)
  64. Acemoglu, Daron (5 January 2009). "The Crisis of 2008: Lessons for and from Economics". Hoover Institution.
  65. Roell, Sophie (December 2011). The best books on Inequality recommended by Daron Acemoglu. Five Books.
  66. Shea, Christopher (24 September 2008). "Anti-bailout economists". The Boston Globe.
  67. Korones, Sarah (2 April 2012). "Q&A: Daron Acemoglu, economist, on why nations fail". ZDNet. Archived from the original on 13 October 2017.
  68. Acemoglu, Daron; Robinson, James A. (11 March 2012). "The Problem With U.S. Inequality". HuffPost. (cached)
  69. Acemoglu, Daron (18 January 2017). "We Are the Last Defense Against Trump". Foreign Policy. Archived from the original on 8 November 2017. (, )
  70. "Over 600 Economists Sign Letter In Support of $10.10 Minimum Wage". Economic Policy Institute. 14 January 2014. Archived from the original on 9 October 2017.
  71. Acemoglu, Daron (January 2001). "Good Jobs versus Bad Jobs". Journal of Labor Economics. 19 (1): 1–21. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.687.4806. doi:10.1086/209978. JSTOR 10.1086/209978. S2CID 2316641.
  72. Acemoglu, Daron; Pischke, Jörn-Steffen (2003). Minimum Wages and On-the-job Training (PDF). Research in Labor Economics. 22. pp. 159–202. doi:10.1016/S0147-9121(03)22005-7. hdl:1721.1/63851. ISBN 978-0-7623-1026-5. ISSN 0147-9121.
  73. Schiller, Ben (17 February 2017). "Economists Are Not Very Enthusiastic About The Idea Of A Universal Basic Income". Fast Company. Archived from the original on 7 November 2017.
  74. Acemoglu, Daron (June 7, 2019). "Why Universal Basic Income Is a Bad Idea". Project Syndicate.
  75. Acemoglu, Daron; Naidu, Suresh; Restrepo, Pascual; Robinson, James A. (March 2014). "Democracy Does Cause Growth". NBER Working Paper No. 20004. doi:10.3386/w20004. Cite journal requires |journal= (help)
  76. Acemoglu, Daron; Naidu, Suresh; Restrepo, Pascual; Robinson, James A. (December 2013). "Democracy, Redistribution and Inequality". NBER Working Paper No. 19746. doi:10.3386/w19746. Cite journal requires |journal= (help)
  77. Acemoglu, Daron; Robnson, James (12 March 2013). "What Bill Gates Got Wrong About Why Nations Fail". Foreign Policy. ...extractive, authoritarian political institutions...
  78. Freeland, Chrystia (1 March 2012). "Dignity and the Wealth of Nations". The New York Times.
  79. Acemoglu, Daron; Robinson, James A. (2012-03-21). "Will China Rule the World?". HuffPost. Archived from the original on 6 November 2017.
  80. Edsall, Thomas B. (April 24, 2019). "Bernie Sanders Scares a Lot of People, and Quite a Few of Them Are Democrats". The New York Times.
  81. Levitt, Steven D. (20 April 2012). "Acemoglu and Robinson Answer Your Questions". Freakonomics. Archived from the original on 6 November 2017.
  82. Acemoglu, Daron; Robinson, James A. (2015). "The Rise and Decline of General Laws of Capitalism". Journal of Economic Perspectives. 29 (1): 3–28. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.687.2487. doi:10.1257/jep.29.1.3. hdl:1721.1/113636. S2CID 14001669. Archived from the original on 2017-02-13.CS1 maint: bot: original URL status unknown (link)
  83. Acemoglu, Daron; Robinson, James A.; Verdier, Thierry (October 2012). "Can't We All Be More Like Scandinavians? Asymmetric Growth and Institutions in an Interdependent World". National Bureau of Economic Research. doi:10.3386/w18441. Cite journal requires |journal= (help)
  84. Acemoglu, Daron; Robinson, James A. (2013). "Economics versus Politics: Pitfalls of Policy Advice". Journal of Economic Perspectives. 27 (2): 173–192. doi:10.1257/jep.27.2.173. hdl:1721.1/82599.
  85. Acemoglu, Daron; Aghion, Philippe (2001). "Deunionization, technical change and inequality". Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy. 55: 229–264. doi:10.1016/s0167-2231(01)00058-6. S2CID 17495766.
  86. Acemoglu, Daron (20 October 2015). "A Scandinavian U.S. Would Be a Problem for the Global Economy". The New York Times.
  87. "Will everyone be worse off if the United States turns social democratic?". Lane Kenworthy. 2012-09-29. Retrieved 2020-10-17.
  88. Acemoglu, Daron; Johnson, Simon; Robinson, James A. (2001). "The Colonial Origins of Comparative Development: An Empirical Investigation". The American Economic Review. 91 (5): 1369–1401. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.475.6366. doi:10.3386/w7771. JSTOR 41724682.
  89. Edsall, Thomas B. (3 November 2016). "Hillary Clinton's Juggling Act". The New York Times.
  90. Sauga, Michael (12 October 2019). "Political Economist Daran Acemoglu: 'Trump Poses a Great Risk to U.S. Democracy'". Der Spiegel.
  91. Giridharadas, Anand (26 August 2011). "For Libya, a Light Hand May Be Best". The New York Times.
  92. "Drug Use Policies". Initiative on Global Markets. 12 December 2011.
  93. "A Letter of Support From the Academic Community: Yes on Amendment 64". Colorado Campaign to Regulate Marijuana Like Alcohol. 2012. Archived from the original on March 4, 2013. Retrieved February 28, 2013.
  94. "School Vouchers". Initiative on Global Markets. 3 April 2012.
  95. Jiang, Jess (26 February 2016). "Economists On Candidates' Proposals: Mostly Bad". NPR.
  96. Gürcanlı, Zeynep (30 March 2011). "İlk Ermeni kökenli Türk büyükelçi Paris'e". Hürriyet (in Turkish). Archived from the original on 16 September 2017.
  97. Düven, Alparslan (30 March 2011). "Paris'e Ermeni asıllı Büyükelçi atanacak iddiası" (in Turkish). Doğan News Agency. Archived from the original on 16 September 2017.
  98. Moraitis, Stratos (30 March 2011). "Ethnic Armenian in Turkey rejects diplomatic post". Greek Reporter. Archived from the original on 16 September 2017.
  99. "Armenian Declines Davutoglu Appointment". Asbarez. 30 March 2011.
  100. Hayrumyan, Naira (30 March 2011). "Analysis: Turkey continues to "earn dividends" on Armenian theme". ArmeniaNow. Archived from the original on 25 October 2017.
  101. Laidler, John (28 April 2015). "Understanding Turkey". Harvard Gazette. Harvard University. Archived from the original on 15 September 2017.
  102. "Inside Turkey's Economy – Interview with Daron Acemoglu". GEDProject. Bertelsmann Stiftung. 22 August 2016. 11:40 "The overall, sort of, unwillingness to come to grips with this, sort of, multiethnicity has, of course, characterized much of the Republican period."
  103. Freeland, Chrystia (6 June 2013). "The perils of authoritarian overreaction". The Globe and Mail.
  104. Acemoglu, Daron (5 June 2013). "Development Won't Ensure Democracy in Turkey". The New York Times.
  105. Acemoglu, Daron (22 May 2014). "The Failed Autocrat: Despite Erdogan's Ruthlessness, Turkey's Democracy Is Still on Track". Foreign Affairs. (archived)
  106. Erciyes, Cem (December 30, 2019). "How will Turkey enter the 'Narrow Corridor'?". Gazete Duvar.
  107. "Acemoglu's Advice to Armenia – Abolish the Oligarchy". civilnet.am. 24 October 2013. Archived from the original on 17 September 2017.CS1 maint: bot: original URL status unknown (link)
  108. Balyan, Varduhi (22 September 2016). "Acemoğlu'ndan Ermenistan ve Diaspora yorumu". Agos (in Turkish). Archived from the original on 16 September 2017. (, )
  109. "Daron Acemoglu: Armenia's Problems Within Its Own Political System". civilnet.am. 10 April 2017. Archived from the original on 17 September 2017.CS1 maint: bot: original URL status unknown (link)
  110. "Հենց նոր հեռախոսազրույց ունեցա հայազգի աշխարհահռչակ տնտեսագետ Դարոն Աճեմօղլուի հետ" (in Armenian). Nikol Pashinyan on Facebook. 13 May 2018.
  111. "Economist Daron Acemoglu to Advise Armenian Government, Says PM Pashinyan". Hetq. 13 May 2018.
  112. "Nikol Pashinyan holds videoconference with Daron Acemoglu". primeminister.am. Prime Minister of the Republic of Armenia. 11 June 2018.
  113. "We had an interesting discussion with Professor Daron #Acemoglu and entrepreneur Noubar #Afeyan in Boston. The socio-economic situation in Armenia, investments, new jobs, public administration #reform, women empowerment were among the topics discussed". AvinyanTigran on Twitter. July 22, 2019.
  114. Arkun, Aram (August 1, 2019). "Deputy Prime Minister Avinyan Speaks at Armenian Business Network Cambridge Event". Armenian Mirror-Spectator.
  115. "Brexit II". Initiative on Global Markets. 12 July 2016. Archived from the original on 17 October 2017.
  116. "Greece". Initiative on Global Markets. 24 February 2015.
  117. Kurtaran, Gokhan (4 August 2015). "EU needs political and economic integration: Acemoglu". Anadolu Agency.
  118. "Greece's Referendum". Initiative on Global Markets. 4 July 2015.
  119. Acemoglu, Daron (14 March 2014). "Ukraine's legacy of serial oligopoly". The Globe and Mail.
  120. "Top 10% Authors (Last 10 Years Publications), as of September 2015". ideas.repec.org. Archived from the original on 5 September 2015.
  121. "The FP Top 100 Global Thinkers". Foreign Policy. 23 November 2010. p. 92. JSTOR 29764933
  122. Davis, William L.; Figgins, Bob; Hedengren, David; Klein, Daniel B. (May 2011). "Economics Professors' Favorite Economic Thinkers, Journals, and Blogs (along with Party and Policy Views)" (PDF). Econ Journal Watch. 8 (2): 139. (archived)
  123. "Why Nations Fail: The Origins of Power, Prosperity, and Poverty". Barnes & Noble.
  124. Pilling, David (30 September 2016). "Crash and learn: should we change the way we teach economics?". Financial Times.
  125. Davidson, Adam (13 March 2012). "Why Some Countries Go Bust". The New York Times.
  126. Mandel, Michael (14 January 2009). "Acemoglu on Growth and Innovation". Bloomberg News.
  127. Shimer 2007.
  128. "John von Neumann Award". Rajk László College for Advanced Studies. Archived from the original on 2014-12-15. Retrieved 2018-08-12. 2007 Daron Acemoglu (MIT)
  129. Tremmel, Pat Vaughan (16 April 2012). "Nemmers Prizes Announced". northwestern.edu.
  130. "Daron Acemoglu earns the Frontiers of Knowledge award for proving the influence of institutions over economic development". bbva.com. 21 February 2017.
  131. Dizikes, Peter (21 February 2017). "Daron Acemoglu wins BBVA Foundation Frontiers of Knowledge Award". news.mit.edu. MIT News Office.
  132. "Daron Acemoglu talk & prize". Toulouse School of Economics.
  133. "2018 Jean-Jacques Laffont prize". jjlaffont.org. L’Association Jean-Jacques Laffont.
  134. "The Narrow Corridor to Liberty: Daron Acemoglu". civilnet.am. 16 February 2019. Archived from the original on 11 July 2019.
  135. "2013 'Presidential Culture and Arts Grand Awards' conferred". Anadolu Agency. 24 December 2013.
  136. "Bilkent Honorary Doctorate Conferred Upon Daron Acemoğlu". bilkent.edu.tr. 7 September 2015.
  137. "Professor Daron Acemoglu – Honorary Degree, Public Lecture and Workshop". bath.ac.uk. 21 March 2017.
  138. "Daron Acemoglu". carnegie.org. Carnegie Corporation of New York. Archived from the original on 20 March 2019.

Sources

This article is issued from Wikipedia. The text is licensed under Creative Commons - Attribution - Sharealike. Additional terms may apply for the media files.